Letter to the Straits Times in response to an economist. My reply should not be taken as thoroughly antagonistic to his position, but more as a expression of concern for the usefulness (and limitations) of market-oriented tools and models, as well as the tendency of modern economics to place the market before man and nature.
- - - - - - -
Dr. Quah (ST, 31 Jan 2005) highlights the pertinent need to evaluate the value of nature using tools that would help policy-makers make better-informed and meaningful decisions on what should be preserved or sacrificed.
However, it could be said that seeking to place a market dollar value on a habitat, species or biodiversity of a locale is an exercise fraught with subjectivity as well as dangerously reductionist in its attempt to subsume the worth of complex and irreplaceable systems into a monetary scheme of value. One could well argue that the little utilised space afforded to largely-empty padangs and under-visited national monuments represents a tremendous opportunity cost lost to real estate developers (as well as the state, being the landlord). But could not the civic and historic value of such public space be likewise appraised? How should one then judge the ‘loss’ suffered by any individual or nation at the draining of a marsh, the extinction of a tree or bird, or the clearing of a green patch? Whose lives would be measurably affected by the eradication of the tiger, the leaf monkey or a mangrove swamp?
Economic assessments of nature that rely solely on marketised notions of real estate value are likely to overlook two vital concepts: the idea of externalities (whereby the consumption of good entails gains or losses that are not factored into its price/cost), and the provision of public goods. (The ongoing debate about the casino proposal could be said to hinge largely on differing views of how significant and manageable the negative externalities of a casino would be.)
More rigorous study of the positive externalities generated by intact eco-systems, as well as the negative externalities which their loss could incur, is certainly warranted to ascertain what their preservation (or destruction) could mean to both individuals and society at large.
Possible correlations include the loss to fisheries (think of all the seafood) from degraded mangrove swamps and coral reefs (which respectively serve as refuges for the fry and adults of many delectable species); the role of dense tree cover (no, Bishan Park doesn’t count) in mitigating ambient temperature and improving air quality and health; the drainage regulation afforded by peat swamps; as well as the psychological significance (stress levels, sense of belonging etc…) of retaining natural areas to the population. Might the steady (and seemingly irrefutable) encroachment of the bulldozer be a substantial factor in the minds of emigrants wanting to live in an environment with more open space and less manicured parkland? What would be the cost too to Singaporeans who might one day have to fly further afar just to catch sight of a creature extinct locally, or simply to find respite from the endless towers of development?
There is also the troubling view that economic development and the preservation of natural spaces is a zero-sum game. As conservationist Ria Tan remarked, where else in the world can one find pristine rainforests, tropical mangroves and rich coral reefs all within 20 minutes of each other? We welcome millions of tourists, many of whom come from lands where biodiversity is prized and learning about nature is a common pursuit. Not every traveller is physically equipped to traverse the rivers of Sarawak or climb the mounts of Borneo. Why not explore the idea of pitching Singapore’s reserves and waters as a safe haven and stopover for elderly or less able visitors who would appreciate a safe plank walk through lush mangroves or forest paths in the morning, with time enough for tea at Raffles Hotel after mid-day?
To this one could add the promise of biochemical miracles that Singapore’s indigenous flora and fauna are just beginning to reveal to researchers.
Economists are often uncomfortable with public goods, as it is difficult to place such items within the conventional framework of discrete supply and effective demand. The provision of street lighting, national defence, basic education and healthcare, transportation networks and urban planning are typically assigned to the tax-collecting state, as private delivery of such goods is hindered by their liability to the free-rider syndrome, i.e. the good’s provision benefits everyone, so there is no incentive for a rational individual to pay for what he could enjoy freely thanks to a less calculative person).
Ecosystems and nature areas share this feature, along with the tremendous (and under-estimated) externalities associated with their existence (or demise). Unless one opts to ring-fence local parks and green areas, and charge each visitor the maximum fee he is willing to pay, rigid econometric models are likely to both underrate the true utility of nature as well as ignore the unquantifiable human values accorded to the sustaining of native biological diversity.
Asad Latif pleads for a balance; it seems to me that by far, the balance of power between nature and ‘development’ has been skewed in favour of the latter, taking not into the account the valid idea that human welfare is linked to nature’s health and that ‘development’ does not have to come at nature’s expense. With land an increasingly scarce and costly commodity, surely it makes sense for Singapore to incentivise the pursuit of activities that create high value from renewable resources (e.g. brainwork by the finance and creative sectors, eco-tourism, tropical bio-medical research) rather than await the implied day when every square inch of soil must contribute to the balance sheet.
A cost benefit analysis can be helpful in gauging the utility of a choice, but the adoption of too narrow a definition of value is likely to result in decisions that sacrifice long term well-being for more immediate (and not necessarily sustainable) revenue streams. Besides, should such an approach be universally prescribed for all facets of life as well? Whether to marry, to have children, to pursue a hobby, embrace a faith, honour our history and leave a legacy? Should we seek to assign a price to everything, and in doing, forget the value of it all?
- - - - - - - -
Economy v environment: Let's talk dollars and sense 31 Jan 2005
I HAVE been reading with some amusement, and perhaps a little frustration, the latest Straits Times coverage on the nature versus economic growth debate in Parliament ('Debate over the price of being green'; ST, Jan 26), as well as the commentary by Institute of South-east Asian Studies fellow Lee Poh Onn on the worth of natural heritage in Singapore ('How much is natural heritage worth?'; ST, Jan 23).
More than 10 years ago, The Straits Times featured in its Life! section a lengthy debate between me, as an academic economist, and Dr Ho Hua Chew, who was at that time president of the Nature Society of Singapore, on precisely the issues discussed today (ST, Oct 29, 1992).
My frustration comes as a result of not seeing more that could have been done to solve, or perhaps more aptly handle, such environmental concerns by the use of well-known and established methods taught in all environmental economics courses across much of the developed world.
In the 1992 article, I explained the merits of techniques such as cost-benefit analysis, valuation of non-market environmental goods and impact analysis in dealing with such problems. It is important, in my view, to attempt to place money values on the environment where it is affected by development projects. It is only by putting such things on a common plate, by deriving values in dollar terms, that some means of comparison and relative worth of projects and policies can be assessed inclusively.
There is not much advantage in listing, as is done traditionally by most nature societies, all the so-called biodiversity and species that face extinction in an attempt to stop a proposed project. On the one hand, there is a development project worth, say, $50 million. On the other, there is a list of 10,000 species of birds, 8,500 types of insects, more than 2,000 species of trees and so on. How is one to make much meaningful sense of this, let alone weigh the merits of the project?
The article by Mr Asad Latif on the economy versus the environment makes more sense in creating awareness that we, as a society, cannot have a so-called 'free lunch' in getting more growth ('Economy v environment? No, it's about achieving balance'; ST, Jan 26). There have to be some sacrifices but more pertinently, there is a need to balance further growth (and with it, employment, consumer goods and so on) with preserving or enhancing nature.
It is important to remind ourselves that Singapore is a land-scarce country and at the same time realise that as more land is devoted to projects, the remaining pristine environment gets smaller.
Ultimately, it depends on what a society wants: more nature or more urbanisation (both have benefits). However, the test of the relative worth of each new project should be based on the economic science of common sense in valuing and comparing in a systematic way the benefits and costs of each proposal.
Euston Quah Teong Ewe (Dr)
Recent Comments